Continuity and Change in American Family Pdf
Abstract
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
References
1 Peter, Laslett , 'Characteristics of the western family considered over time', Journal of Family History 2 (1977), 90.Google Scholar
2 Hajnal, , 'Two kinds of pre-industrial household formation system', in Richard, Wall et al. eds., Family forms in historic Europe (Cambridge, 1983), 65, 69Google Scholar. The formation rules of the contrasting joint household systems are: (a) earlier marriage for men and rather early marriage for women (mean ages at first marriage are under 26 for men and under 21 for women); (b) a young married couple often start life together in a household of which an older couple are in charge; and (c) households with several married couples may split to form two or more households, each containing one or more couples.
3 Also see his 'European marriage patterns in perspective', pp. 101–43Google Scholar in Glass, D. V. and Eversley, D. E. C. eds., Population in history (London, 1963).Google Scholar
4 Simon, Kuznets , Modern economic growth: rate, structure and spread (New Haven, Conn., 1966).Google Scholar
5 Kang, Chao , Man and land in Chinese history: an economic analysis (Stanford, 1986), 8–9, 26–30.Google Scholar
6 A historian from Canada, David Levine, has developed a Marxisant version of the model in a number of studies; see Reproducing families: the political economy of English population history (Cambridge, 1987)Google Scholar. Emmanuel Todd, a French sociologist, is responsible for the most sweeping elaboration: The explanation of ideology: family structure and social systems, trans. David, Garrioch (Oxford, 1985).Google Scholar
7 In The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism, trans Talcott, Parsons (New York, 1958; orig. pub. 1904–1905)Google Scholar, Weber, of course, used the aphorisms of Benjamin Franklin to exemplify post-Calvinist capitalist ethics.
8 Warren, Sanderson , 'Quantitative aspects of marriage, fertility and family limitation in nineteenth-century America: another application of the Coale specifications', Demography 16 (1979), 339–58.Google Scholar
9 Cases included are Sturbridge (1780–1799), Northampton (1750–1799), Nantucket (1780–1839), Deerfield (1781–1800), and Hingham (1781–1800) in Massachusetts; middle colony Quakers (1756–1785); Prince George's County Maryland (1750–1800); and Virginia gentry women (1800–1839). From Table 1 (pp. 88–9) in Wells, Robert V. , 'The population of England's colonies in America: old English or new Americans?', Population Studies 46 (1992), 85–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
10 Yasukichi, Yasuba , Birth rates of the white population of the United States, 1800–1860: an economic study (Baltimore, 1962), 61–2.Google Scholar
11 If the birth record begins in 1700, and the first tabulated marriage cohort begins in 1720, it is obvious that no one who married over age 30 in the 1720–1729 period can enter the calculation. The way around this bias is to organize the early data by birth cohorts. There is, as Steven Ruggles has shown, an opposite bias in studies of marriage age based on the linkage of birth to marriage records; the calculation is biased downward because those who migrate before marriage are typically lost to observation; see his 'Migration, marriage and mortality: correcting sources of bias in English family reconstitutions', Population Studies 46 (1992), 507–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
12 Nor is this difficulty novel. The English radical William Godwin correctly observed that the Hingham, Massachusetts, ratio of marriages to births, which Malthus had cited in favour of his argument for early marriage in America, was well within the values reported for western European populations. However, the child-woman ratio for the town was not attained nationally by the white population until 1870, after more than a half-century of declining child-woman ratios. Godwin was right about the numbers, but quite wrong about the larger picture. Malthus made an empirical mistake, but had the explanation more correctly: an object lesson, if a bit dangerous, for historical demographers today. See Smith, Daniel Scott , 'Underregistration and bias in probate records: an analysis of data from eighteenth-century Hingham, Massachusetts', William and Mary Quarterly 3rd ser. 32 (1975), 102–3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13 As Hajnal notes, a high householder rate for young married men is compatible with a stem-household formation system in which the older couple retires at the time of marriage of the heir.
14 Steven, Ruggles , Prolonged connections: the rise of the extended family in nineteenth-century England and America (Madison, Wisc., 1987), 3–12.Google Scholar
15 Seward, Rudy Ray , The American family: a demographic history (Beverly Hills, 1978), Table 3.6 (p. 86)Google Scholar. For the censuses between 1850 and 1870, Seward had to infer generational depth from a combination of surnames and age differences among household members. It seems likely that the 1880 figure is closer to the mark than the inferred percentages for the 1850 to 1870 censuses.
16 See my 'Historical change in the household structure of the elderly in economically developed societies', in Fogel, Robert W. et al. eds., Aging: stability and change in the family (New York, 1981), 107.Google Scholar
17 Morgan, Edmund S. , The Puritan family: religion and domestic relations in seventeenth-century New England (New York, 2nd ed., 1966), 79.Google Scholar
18 Entry for April 19, 1788, Diary of John Quincy Adams, eds. Allen, David Grayson et al. (Cambridge, Mass., 1981), vol. ii, p. 393.Google Scholar
19 This phrase, from Genesis 2:24, was repeated in the Anglican marriage ceremony. See The book of common prayer, 1559, ed. John, Booty (Washington, D.C., 1976).Google Scholar
20 The fact that contracts of indentured servants made in England were purchased by others in America make it very unlikely that there would be a kinship tie between master and indentured servant.
21 In England, the average for 62 communities, 1574–1821, was 106.6 males per 100 females; Peter, Laslett , 'Mean household size in England since the sixteenth century', in Laslett, ed., Household and family in past-time (Cambridge, 1972), Table 4.13 (p. 152).Google Scholar
22 Galenson, David W. , White servitude in colonial America: an economic analysis (New York, 1981), Tables 2.1, 2.2 (pp. 24–5)Google Scholar. It is likely that males were more willing than were females to become servants in America because the latter had to serve for a shorter period; ibid., Table 7.1 (p. 104).
23 Ann, Kussmaul , Servants in husbandry in early modern England (New York, 1981), 4, 145.Google Scholar
24 Morgan, Edmund S. , American slavery, American freedom: the ordeal of colonial Virginia (New York, 1975), 126–8.Google Scholar
25 Steinfeld, Robert J. , The invention of free labor: the employment relation in English and America law and culture, 1350–1870 (Chapel Hill, N.C., 1991), 122–72Google Scholar; Bernard, Elbaum , 'Why apprenticeship persisted in Britain but not in the United States', Journal of Economic History 49 (1989), 337–49.Google Scholar
26 Figures are from McCusker, John J. and Menard, Russell R. , The economy of British America, 1607–1789 (Chapel Hill, N.C., 1985), pp. 103, 136, 172, 203.Google Scholar
27 Counting slaves as members of their owners' households leads to very high figures for mean household size, as for example that of 43.6 on the island of Tobago in 1770 or 9.5 in South Carolina in 1790. However, mean household size for whites in the latter case was only 5.5; see Rossiter, W. S. , A century of population growth (Washington, 1909)Google Scholar. See also Wells, Robert V. , The population of the British colonies in America before 1776 (Princeton, 1975), 300.Google Scholar
28 Malthus, Thomas Robert , An essay on the principle of population, as it affects the future improvement of society (New York, 1960; orig. pub. 1798), pp. 9, 11–12.Google Scholar
29 See, most notably, Yasukichi, Yasuba , Birth ratesGoogle Scholar, and Richard, Easterlin , 'Population change and farm settlement in the northern United States', Journal of Economic History 36 (1976), 45–75Google Scholar. Variations in the availability of land are not the entire story of American fertility differentials and decline. For a review of the issues, see my '"Early" fertility decline in America: a problem in family history', Journal of Family History 12 (1987), 73–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
30 Domar, Evsey D. , 'The causes of slavery or serfdom: a hypothesis', Journal of Economic History 30 (1970), 18–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar. for the value of the Domar hypothesis as a framework for early American history, see Solow, Barbara L. , 'Slavery and colonization', in Solow, ed., Slavery and the rise of the Atlantic system (New York, 1991), 21–43, esp. pp. 35–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
31 For the argument and a discussion of the migration mechanism, see my 'A Malthusian-frontier interpretation of United States demographic history before c. 1815', in Woodrow, Borah , Jorge, Hardoy , and Stelter, Gilbert A. eds., Urbanization in the Americas: the background in comparative perspective (Ottawa, 1980), 15–24.Google Scholar
32 Smith, D. S. , '"All in some degree related to each other": a demographic and comparative resolution of the anomaly of New England kinship', American Historical Review 94 (1989), 44–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
33 Smith, D. S. , 'Female householding in late 18th-century America and the problem of poverty', Journal of Social History 28 (forthcoming, Fall, 1994).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34 Bernand, Richard M. and Vinovskis, Maris A. , 'The female school teacher in antebellum America', Journal of Social History 3 (1977), 332–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar; David, Tyack and Elisabeth, Hansot , Learning together: a history of coeducation in American schools (New Haven, Conn., 1990), 48–51.Google Scholar
35 Ester, Boserup , The conditions of agricultural growth: the economics of agrarian change under population pressure (Chicago, 1965).Google Scholar
36 The high sex ratio among overseas immigrants ensured that female marriage ages were reduced more dramatically than male; see Jacques, Henripin , La population Canadienne au debut du XVllle siècle (Paris, 1954), 96Google Scholar; Hubert, Charbonneau et al. , Naissance d'une population: les Francois établis au Canada au XVIIe siècle (Montreal, 1987), 71Google Scholar; McInnis, R. M. , 'The fall in fertility in nineteenth-century Canada' (unpublished paper for IUSSP conference on the peopling of the Americas, Veracruz, Mexico, 1992), 10Google Scholar; and Robert, Ross , 'The age at marriage of white South Africans, 1700–1951', in Christopher, Fyfe and David, McMaster eds., African historical demography (Edinburgh, 1981), vol. ii., 487–98.Google Scholar
37 David, Levine , Family formation in an age of nascent capitalism (New York, 1977), 16, 61.Google Scholar
38 See Gutmann, Myron P. , Toward the modern economy: early industry in Europe, 1500–1800 (New York, 1988), 115–93Google Scholar; Spagnoli, Paul G. , 'Industrialization, proletarianization, and marriage: a reconsideration', Journal of Family History 8 (1983), 230–47CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed; Lehning, James R. , 'Nuptiality and rural industry: families and labour in the French countryside', Journal of Family History 8 (1983), 333–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gullickson, Gay L. , Spinners and weavers of Auffay: rural industry and the sexual division of labour in a French village, 1750–1850 (Cambridge, 1986), 129–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Ulrich, Pfister , 'Proto-industrialization and demographic change: the canton of Zurich revisited', Journal of European Economic History 18 (1989), 629–62Google Scholar. More studies have shown that protoindustrialization was associated with population growth than with earlier and more universal marriage. Migration is the obvious source of population increase for small localities. While variation in the number of marriages correlates with price changes indicating protoindustrial activity, these relationships could be driven by migration into and out of the localities so affected rather than by the incidence of marriages in the currently unmarried population. See also Continuity and Change 8 (2), the special issue on protoindustrialization.
39 Greven, Philip J. Jr , Four generations: population, land and family in colonial Andover, Massachusetts (Ithaca, N.Y., 1970)Google Scholar; Smith, Daniel Scott , 'The demographic history of colonial New England', Journal of Economic History 32 (1972), 176–82.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
40 Pope, Clayne L. , 'Households on the American frontier: the distribution of income and wealth in Utah, 1850–1900', in Galenson, David W. ed., Markets in history: economic studies of the past (New York, 1989), 164–70Google Scholar; Jeremy, Atack and Fred, Bateman , To their own soil: agriculture in the antebellum North (Ames, Iowa, 1987), 92–101.Google Scholar
41 Elliott, Vivien Brodsky , 'Single women in the London marriage market: age, status, and mobility', in Outhwaite, R. B. ed., Marriage and society: studies in the social history of marriage (New York, 1982), 81–100Google Scholar. Even more suggestive in the doubts it raises about the familial mechanisms behind a Malthusian homeostatic regime is Elliott's finding that paternal death forced young women to migrate to London as servants and thereby delayed their entry into marriage. Some 64 per cent of migrant women had lost their fathers by the time of marriage compared to 47 per cent of women native to the high-mortality environment of the city. This micro-level result conflicts, of course, with the Malthusian homeostatic logic that connects higher mortality to the opening of economic niches and thus to earlier marriage of men and, implicitly, consequently of women, and thereupon to a subsequent increase in fertility and population growth. It should be noted that most of the empirical studies of both the Malthusian and the protoindustrial models have dealt with short-term fluctuations and long-term trends rather than individual-level behaviour.
42 Helena, Chojnacka , 'Nuptiality patterns in an agrarian society', Population Studies 30 (1976), 203–26Google Scholar; Coale, Ansley J. , Barbara, Anderson and Erna, Harm , Human fertility in Russia since the nineteenth century (Princeton, 1979), 147–78.Google Scholar
43 Daniel Little has noted the thinness of evidence available to test the validity of the Malthusian model as applied to the historic Chinese case; see his Understanding peasant China: case studies in the philosophy of social science (New Haven, Conn., 1986), 108–18, 130–6, 143–4Google Scholar. Nuptiality has shown flexibility in Asian societies in recent decades, decreasing substantially in both south and southeast Asia. In India during this century (1901–81), female mean age at first marriage rose from 13.0 to 18.4, and male from 20.4 to 23.4; see Agarwala, S. N. , India's population problems (Bombay, 3rd ed., 1985) 99–113Google Scholar. Also see Richard, Leete , 'The post-demographic transition in east and south-east Asia: similarities and contrasts with Europe', Population Studies 41 (1987), 187–206.Google Scholar
44 Klein, Herbert S. and Stanley, Engerman , 'Fertility differentials between slaves in the United States and the British West Indies: a note on lactation practices and their possible implication', William and Mary Quarterly, 4rd ser. 35 (1978), 357–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
45 Fogel, Robert William , Without consent or contact: the rise and fall of American slavery (New York, 1989), 148–51Google Scholar; Malone, Ann Patton , Sweet chariot: slave family and household structure in nineteenth-century Louisiana (Chapel Hill, N.C., 1992), 175–7Google Scholar; Paul, Escott , Slavery remembered: a record of twentieth-century slave narratives (Chapel Hill, N.C., 1979), 46–53Google Scholar; Brenda, Stevenson , 'Distress and discord in Virginia slave families, 1830–1860', in Carol, Bleser ed., In joy and sorrow: women, family, and marriage in the Victorian South, 1830–1900 (New York, 1991), 103–24Google Scholar; and Patrick, Manning , Slavery and African life: occidental, oriental, and African slave trades (Cambridge, 1990), 55.Google Scholar
46 Of course, here is another of the unstated assumptions behind the Malthusian model: marriage was preferable to remaining single and earlier marriage better than later. No doubt this assumption has some validity, since the options open to the unmarried, particularly spinsters, were quite bleak.
47 A valuable comparative study of slavery and serfdom is provided by Peter, Kolchin , Unfree labor: American slavery and Russian serfdom (Cambridge, Mass., 1987)Google Scholar. Also see Peter, Laslett , 'Household and family on the slave plantations of the U.S.A.', in his Family life and illicit love in earlier generations: essays in historical sociology (Cambridge, 1977), 233–60.Google Scholar
48 For an interesting exception, see Hughes, Sarah S. , 'Slaves for hire: the allocation of black labor in Elizabeth City County, Virginia, 1782–1810', William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd Ser. 35 (1978), 260–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
49 Cody, Cheryll A. , For everything there is a season: the family and demographic lives of enslaved people on the Ball plantations, 1720–1865 (book in manuscript, 1992), Chapter 5.Google Scholar
50 Klein, Herbert S. , African slavery in Latin America and the Caribbean (New York, 1986), 168–77.Google Scholar
51 Ralph, Shlomowitz , 'The squad system on postbellum cotton plantations', in Burton, Orville Vernon and McMath, Robert C. Jr eds., Towards a new South ? Studies in post-civil war Southern communities (Westport, Conn., 1980), 265–80Google Scholar; and Shaffer, John W. , Family and farm: agrarian change and household organization in the Loire valley, 1500–1900 (Albany, N.Y., 1982).Google Scholar
53 Gunnlaugsson, Gísli Ágúst , Family and household in Iceland, 1801–1930 (Uppsala, 1988)Google Scholar, and 'Living arrangements of the elderly in a changing society: the case of Iceland, 1890–1930', (paper presented at the 1991 SSHA meeting, New Orleans, published in Continuity and Change 8 (1), 1993, pp. 103–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
54 Steven, Ruggles , 'Living arrangements of the elderly in America, 1880–1980'Google Scholar, and Richard, Wall , 'Elderly persons and the members of their households in England and Wales from pre-industrial times to the present day' (papers presented at the New Orleans meetings of the Social Science History Association, 1991).Google Scholar
55 See my 'The curious history of theorizing about the history of the Western nuclear family', Social Science History 17 (3), 1993, 325–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
56 See my 'Parental power and marriage patterns: an analysis of historical trends in Hingham, Massachusetts', Journal of Marriage and the Family 35 (1973), 419–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Muriel, Nazzari , Disappearance of the dowry: women, families, and social change in Sao Paulo, Brazil, 1600–1900 (Stanford, 1991).Google Scholar
57 For an emphasis on the long-run development of such values, see North, Douglass C. , Institutions, institutional change and economic performance (Cambridge, 1990).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
fishbournemoothoung.blogspot.com
Source: https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/continuity-and-change/article/american-family-and-demographic-patterns-and-the-northwest-european-model/E205CB7B401B50FC721B8539C66AC233
0 Response to "Continuity and Change in American Family Pdf"
Post a Comment